Menu Costs and the Neutrality of money OR。 Andrew S Caplin; Daniel F Spulber The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 102, No 4.(Nov,, 1987), pp. 703-726 Stable url: http:/inks.jstororg/sici?sici=0033-5533%28198711%29102%03a4%03c703%3amcatno%3e2.0.c0%03b2-6 The Quarterly Journal of Economics is currently published by The MIT Press Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/about/terms.htmlJstOr'sTermsandConditionsofUseprovidesinpartthatunlessyouhaveobtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the jsTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that ap on the screen or printed page of such transmission STOR is an independent not-for-profit organization dedicated to and preserving a digital archive of scholarly journals. For more information regarding JSTOR, please contact support @jstor. org http://www.jstor.org Tue may1511:40212007
Menu Costs and the Neutrality of Money Andrew S. Caplin; Daniel F. Spulber The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 102, No. 4. (Nov., 1987), pp. 703-726. Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0033-5533%28198711%29102%3A4%3C703%3AMCATNO%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6 The Quarterly Journal of Economics is currently published by The MIT Press. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/about/terms.html. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/journals/mitpress.html. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is an independent not-for-profit organization dedicated to and preserving a digital archive of scholarly journals. For more information regarding JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. http://www.jstor.org Tue May 15 11:40:21 2007
THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Vol. CII November 1987 Issue 4 MENU COSTS AND THE NEUTRALITY OF MONEY* ANDREW S. CAPLIN AND DANIEL F SPULBER A model of endogenous price adjustment under money growth is presented Firms follow(s, S)pricing policies, and price revisions are imperfectly synchronize In the aggregate, price stickiness disappears, and money is neutral. The connection etween firm price adjustment and relative price variability in the presence of onetary growth is also investigated. The results contrast with those obtained in models with exogenous fixed timing of price adjustment. INTRODUCTION Historically determined nominal prices can lead to inertia in the aggregate level of prices, leaving room for monetary shocks to influence real variables. Formal models connecting the microeco nomic behavior of nominal prices with aggregate price stickiness lude models with staggered price and decisions [Fischer 1977; Taylor, 1980; Blanchard, 1983; Parkin, 1986], models with partial adjustment of prices(e. g, Rotemberg [1982]), and the more recent"menu cost"models of Akerlof and Yellen [1985], Blanchard and Kiyotaki 1985], and Mankiw [1985]. We present an alternative aggregate model with microeconomic price stickiness that empha sizes the importance of endogenous timing of price adjustments The model provides conditions under which money shocks have no real effects a number of macroeconomic models of price stickiness have a common microeconomic base: infrequent but large changes in *We thank a o. SES-82-19121. The paper was nted at the WBER Progress o the noc metrist society, Cambridge, M A 1 985, and at the e 1987 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of The quarterly Journal of Economics, ovember 1987
THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Vol. CII November 1987 Issue 4 MENU COSTS AND THE NEUTRALITY OF MONEY* ANDREWS. CAPLINAND DANIELF. SPULBER A model of endogenous price adjustment under money growth is presented. Firms follow (s,S) pricing policies, and price revisions are imperfectly synchronized. In the aggregate, price stickiness disappears, and money is neutral. The connection between firm price adjustment and relative price variability in the presence of monetary growth is also investigated. The results contrast with those obtained in models with exogenous fixed timing of price adjustment. Historically determined nominal prices can lead to inertia in the aggregate level of prices, leaving room for monetary shocks to influence real variables. Formal models connecting the microeconomic behavior of nominal prices with aggregate price stickiness include models with staggered price and wage decisions [Fischer, 1977; Taylor, 1980; Blanchard, 1983; Parkin, 19861, models with partial adjustment of prices (e.g., Rotemberg [1982]), and the more recent "menu cost" models of Akerlof and Yellen [1985], Blanchard and Kiyotaki [1985], and Mankiw [1985]. We present an alternative aggregate model with microeconomic price stickiness that emphasizes the importance of endogenous timing of price adjustments. The model provides conditions under which money shocks have no real effects. A number of macroeconomic models of price stickiness have a common microeconomic base: infrequent but large changes in *We thank Andrew Abel, Roland Benabou, Olivier Blanchard, Dennis Carlton, Stanley Fischer, Benjamin Friedman, Barry Nalebuff, William Nordhaus, David Romer, Julio Rotemberg, Eytan Sheshinski, John Veitch, and an anonymous referee for valuable comments. Spulber's research was supported by the National Science Foundation under Grant No. SES-82-19121. The paper was presented at the Fifth World Congress of the Econometric Society, Cambridge, MA, 1985, and at the NBER Program in Economic Fluctuations Conference, October, 1985. o 1987 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1987
QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS nominal variables are assumed to be more economical than frequent small changes. The models also share the assumption that the time between successive price revisions is preset, and hence unresponsive to shocks to the economy. This assumption is questionable both at the microeconomic level and in the aggregate. Formal microeco nomic models(e. g, Sheshinski and Weiss [1983 ])strongly suggest that more rapid inflation will shorten the time between price revisions. Empirical evidence against the fixed timing assumption is presented by Cecchetti [1986] and Liebermann and Zilbefarb [1985]. At the aggregate level large monetary shocks may increase the number of agents revising their nominal prices in a given period This in turn reduces the extent of price level inertia. An important open question remains: what are the real effects of monetary shocks with endogenous timing of price revisions? The present paper assumes that individual firms adjust their prices using(s, S)pricing policies of Sheshinski and Weiss [1977, 183]. To model asynchronization, we make a cross-sectional assumption on initial prices. The price level is derived endoge nously by aggregating across firms. aggregate price stickiness then vanishes despite the presence of nominal price rigidity and imper fectly synchronized price revisions. The presence of relative price variability as a consequence of inflation is also observed endogenously through aggregation of cross-sectional price data. A simple formula is derived linking nominal price adjustment by firms with cross-sectional variability of inflation rates The basic model is outlined in Section II. The neutrality proposition is presented in Section III. In Section iv the model is applied to study relative price variability. Section V provides further discussion of the model and its assumptions. Conclusions are given in Section VI. II. THE MODEI IIA. The Aggregate Setting We provide an aggregate model of price dynamics with individ ual firms pursuing asynchronous(s, S) pricing policies. The struc ture of the aggregate model is kept as simple as possible to highlight the distinction between our model and others with asynchronous ts of nomina ption is rotemberg [1983]who considers instead increasing marginal 1. An e
704 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS nominal variables are assumed to be more economical than frequent small changes.' The models also share the assumption that the time between successive price revisions is preset, and hence unresponsive to shocks to the economy. This assumption is questionable both at the microeconomic level and in the aggregate. Formal microeconomic models (e.g., Sheshinski and Weiss [1983]) strongly suggest that more rapid inflation will shorten the time between price revisions. Empirical evidence against the fixed timing assumption is presented by Cecchetti [I9861 and Liebermann and Zilbefarb [1985]. At the aggregate level large monetary shocks may increase the number of agents revising their nominal prices in a given period. This in turn reduces the extent of price level inertia. An important open question remains: what are the real effects of monetary shocks with endogenous timing of price revisions? The present paper assumes that individual firms adjust their prices using (s,S) pricing policies of Sheshinski and Weiss [1977, 19831. To model asynchronization, we make a cross-sectional assumption on initial prices. The price level is derived endogenously by aggregating across firms. Aggregate price stickiness then vanishes despite the presence of nominal price rigidity and imperfectly synchronized price revisions. The presence of relative price variability as a consequence of inflation is also observed endogenously through aggregation of cross-sectional price data. A simple formula is derived linking nominal price adjustment by firms with cross-sectional variability of inflation rates. The basic model is outlined in Section 11. The neutrality proposition is presented in Section 111. In Section IV the model is applied to study relative price variability. Section V provides further discussion of the model and its assumptions. Conclusions are given in Section V1. IIA. The Aggregate Setting We provide an aggregate model of price dynamics with individual firms pursuing asynchronous (s,S) pricing policies. The structure of the aggregate model is kept as simple as possible to highlight the distinction between our model and others with asynchronous 1. An exception is Rotemberg [I9831who considers instead increasing marginal costs of nominal price revisions
MENU COSTS AND THE NEUTRALITY OF MONEY price and wage decisions. These alternative models frequently assume a staggered pattern of timing(e. g, Akerlof [1969 Fischer [1977, Taylor 1980), and Blanchard [1983]) Money growth is subject to continuous shocks. The stochastic process governing monetary growth is taken as exogenous by all firms in the economy. Let M()denote the logarithm of the money supply at time t, where time is measured continuously We assume that the money supply process is increasing over time and does not ASSUMPTION 1. Monotonicity and Continuity. The money supply does not decrease over time, M(t2)2M(t,) for t2 2t1. Also, the money supply process is continuous in the time parameter t Normalize such that M(0)=0 The monotonicity assumption will rule out periods of deflation. The continuity assumption allows a simple characterization of firm pricing policies. The assumption also plays a role in analyzing the cross-sectional behavior of prices. This issue is taken up below.The monetary process is sufficiently general as to accommodate feed back rules. We shall consider particular examples of monetary es bel There is a continuum of firms in the economy indexed by i E [0, 1]. All firms face identical demand and cost conditions. The assumed microeconomic structure is based on the menu cost model of Sheshinski and Weiss [1977, 1983]. Let qi (t)and Q (t)represen firm i's nominal price and the aggregate price index, respectively with pi (t)and P(t)their respective logarithms. The aggregate price index, P(t), is derived endogenously below from individual firm prices. It is convenient to express firm is real price, q(t)/Q(t),in log form, ri (t), t)-ln[q(t)/?(t)], for all E [o, 1]. We take ri (O)as given The aggregate price index Q(t)is determined endogenously by aggregating individual firms' nominal prices qi(t). The index is assumed to depend only on the frequency distribution over nominal prices. Because firms have menu costs of price adjustment, prices may remain dispersed in the long run. Thus, the set of observed prices at any date may be described by a time-dependent frequency distribution function, say G (q). The index is assumed also to 2. In general, the money growth process may be set as a feedback rule based
MENU COSTS AND THE NEUTRaITY OF MONEY 705 price and wage decisions. These alternative models frequently assume a staggered pattern of timing (e.g., Akerlof [1969], Fischer [1977], Taylor [1980], and Blanchard [1983]). Money growth is subject to continuous shocks. The stochastic process governing monetary growth is taken as exogenous by all firms in the e~onomy.~ Let M(t) denote the logarithm of the money supply at time t, where time is measured continuously. We assume that the money supply process is increasing over time and does not make discrete jumps. ASSUMPTION1. Monotonicity and Continuity. The money supply does not decrease over time, M(t,) rM(t,) for t, 2 t,. Also, the money supply process is continuous in the time parameter t. Normalize such that M (0) = 0. The monotonicity assumption will rule out periods of deflation. The continuity assumption allows a simple characterization of firm pricing policies. The assumption also plays a role in analyzing the cross-sectional behavior of prices. This issue is taken up below. The monetary process is sufficiently general as to accommodate feedback rules. We shall consider particular examples of monetary processes below. There is a continuum of firms in the economy indexed by i E [0,1]. All firms face identical demand and cost conditions. The assumed microeconomic structure is based on the menu cost model of Sheshinski and Weiss [1977, 19831. Let qi(t) and Q(t) represent firm i's nominal price and the aggregate price index, respectively, with pi(t) and P(t) their respective logarithms. The aggregate price index, P(t), is derived endogenously below from individual firm prices. It is convenient to express firm i's real price, q(t)lQ(t), in log form, ri(t), for all i E [0,1]. We take ri(0) as given. The aggregate price index Q (t) is determined endogenously by aggregating individual firms' nominal prices qi(t). The index is assumed to depend only on the frequency distribution over nominal prices. Because firms have menu costs of price adjustment, prices may remain dispersed in the long run. Thus, the set of observed prices at any date may be described by a time-dependent frequency distribution function, say G,(q). The index is assumed also to 2. In general, the money growth process may be set as a feedback rule based on the history of output
QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS satisfy homogeneity; when nominal prices double, so does the ASSUMPTION 2. Symmetric Price Index. The aggregate price index Q(t)depends only on the frequency distribution of nominal prices and satisfies homogeneity: (2)Q(t)=Q(G,(q)), where G (q)is the proportion of firms i∈[0,1 such that q:(t)≤q, 3)if G, (q)-GL (q) for all q, then xQ(t,)-Q(t2), for any ti, t2 20 This condition is satisfied by a wide variety of common price indices.An example of a price index that satisfies Assumption 2 is a simple average of nominal prices based on their frequency distribu tion,Q(t)=adG (q). More generally, let Q(t) w(q, G ())qdG (q), where w(, G)represents weights as a function of prices q and the distribution of nominal prices G. The assump tion requires the weights to satisfy w(q, G, )-w(g, Gi, ) when G, ( q)-G (q) for all q. An example of such a set of weights is w(q, G)-ql/ adG(q) IIB. The Market Setting Consumer demand is assumed to depend only on the firm s real price and on real money balances. Writing the arguments in log form, consumer demand faced by firm i, Ti, is defined by Ti (t)=r(r: (t), M(t)-P(t)), where r (t)and M(t)-P(t)are the log of firm i's price and the lo of real balances, respectively. One rationale for this is to assume that real balances enter consumer utility functions, as in, for example, Rotemberg [1982, 1983]. Note also that all firms can have Individual firms set s and S taking the price level as exogenous S, the index endogenously determines P(O O)relative to the exe 4. Blanchard and Kiyotaki [1985]and Ball and Romer 1986] derive symmetric price indices based on an underlying symmetric utility framework dependent of future prices rules out Benabou [1985a real money balances may also influence real demand. For present purposes, Proposition 1 will allow us to ignore this potentially complex depender
706 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS satisfy homogeneity; when nominal prices double, so does the index.3 ASSUMPTION2. Symmetric Price Index. The aggregate price index Q(t) depends only on the frequency distribution of nominal prices and satisfies homogeneity: (2) Q (t) = Q (G,(q)), where Gt(q) is the proportion of firms i E [0,1] such that q,(t) i q, (3) if G,,(q) = Gt2(hq) for all q, then XQ(t,) = Q(t,), for any t,, t, r 0. This condition is satisfied by a wide variety of common price in dice^.^ An example of a price index that satisfies Assumption 2 is a simple average of nominal prices based on their frequency distribution, Q(t) = fqd~t(q).More generally, let Q(t) = f w (q,Gt(. ))qdGt (q), where w (q,G) represents weights as a function of prices q and the distribution of nominal prices G. The assumption requires the weights to satisfy w(q,GtI) = w(hq, G,,) when Gtl(q) = Gt2(Xq) for all q. An example of such a set of weights is w(q,G) = q/f qdG(q). IIB. The Market Setting Consumer demand is assumed to depend only on the firm's real price and on real money balances. Writing the arguments in log form, consumer demand faced by firm i, ri, is defined by (4) r,(t) = r(ri(t), M(t) -P(t)), where ri(t) and M(t) -P(t) are the log of firm i's price and the log of real balances, re~~ectively.~ One rationale for this is to assume that real balances enter consumer utility functions, as in, for example, Rotemberg [1982,1983]. Note also that all firms can have 3. Individual firms set s and S taking the price level as exogenously given. However, for given levels s and S , the index endogenously determines P(0):will the exogenous and endogenous indices be consistent? The answer is generally no: however, if we associate higher real balances with higher levels of s and S , there will be some initial specification of real balances guaranteeing this static consistency, since higher real balances raise the desired average real price, raising the endogenous level of P(0)relative to the exogenous level. 4. Blanchard and Kiyotaki [I9851 and Ball and Romer [I9861 derive symmetric price indices based on an underlying symmetric utility framework. 5. The assumption that demand is independent of future prices rules out consumer speculation. Benabou [1985a] presents an analysis of optimal pricing policies in the face of consumer storage and speculation. In principle, the future path of real money balances may also influence real demand. For present purposes, Proposition 1will allow us to ignore this potentially complex dependence